“Prize-Grants” or Patents for Pharmaceutical Innovation?

Over at the American Enterprise Institute’s online magazine, Arnold Kling has proposed “prize-grants” in favor of patents for pharmaceutical research. Kling dislikes patents:

Patents have always been a problematic way to promote innovation. They raise prices of products far above marginal cost. They impose legal costs involved in obtaining, attacking, and defending patents. They provide an artificially high incentive to develop substitute products that devalue the patented invention. They create an artificial disincentive to develop complementary products, because the high price of the patented product limits its market penetration, adversely affecting would-be product complements.

These drawbacks are well recognized, and a better alternative would certainly be most welcome. The question is: Can there be a better alternative? Kling’s “prize-grant” has the features of both a prize and a patent:

The prize-grant would differ from an ordinary prize in the following ways:

  • The criteria for winning the prize would typically be first suggested by the researchers, with funding institutions then assigning a value for the prize, prior to the research.
  • Prizes often would be for incremental achievements, not just for spectacular accomplishments.
  • Large pharmaceutical companies and other private firms would be just as eligible as nonprofit researchers to receive prize-grants.

We can think of the current intellectual-property regime in medical research as a grant-prize approach in which the prize is a patent. However, prize-grants differ from patents in the following ways:

  • The prize for a successful result is specified by the funding institution. With a patent, the value of the prize is determined in part by patient demand but also by the purchasing rules of insurance companies and governments, by legal jousting, and by gaming of the system.
  • Useful research that does not result in a patentable product gets rewarded under prize-grants, whereas under the patent system such research does not get rewarded.
  • Regardless of the outcome of the research undertaken in pursuit of a prize-grant, findings would be immediately placed in the public domain. In contrast, patents set a term of monopoly on the use of information, during which the prices of patented products can be set far above production cost.

It is a very interesting idea, which I hope Professor Kling continues to develop. By way of constructive criticism, here are some obstacles that need to be overcome:

  • How to determine the value of the prize-grant? If the funder is a passive responder with a limited budget, it needs some rule by which to prioritize. There is no way to determine, before the invention is on the market, what it will be worth. That is the great (often unsung) virtue of patents: They do not guarantee one penny of profit. The market determines the value of the product and its ownership can be traded in the capital market during its entire life-cycle, giving continuous signals to other innovators.
  • This is related to the problem of “incremental innovation”, which I have always thought exceedingly difficult to reward by prizes. Prizes have succeeded when they are given out for “big kahunas”. The most exciting modern prizes are likely those put forward by X Prize Foundation. One of its prizes “is a $30 million competition for the first privately funded team to send a robot to the moon, travel 500 meters and transmit video, images and data back to the Earth. This is an outcome with two attributes: It is remarkably huge; and it can be independently verified without much quibbling, even by non-experts. It is easy to see how prize-grants for incremental pharmaceutical innovation (e.g. another painkiller) could become bogged down in disagreement, no matter how well specified the outcomes are when the prize is announced.
  • Kling also cites Peter Huber’s excellent new book, The Cure in The Code, as evidence that the clinical trials and other hoops through which pharmaceutical innovators must jump are harmful to innovation. However, these are mostly erected by the Food and Drug Administration, not patent law. The two intersect in U.S. law, but only because Congress says so. The FDA itself needs significant reform to stop impeding innovation.

On the other hand, there would be a great benefit to a system like that promoted by Kling, which Kling himself does not describe. Pharmaceutical enterprises are corporate bureaucracies that blend R&D functions with sales and marketing, regulatory affairs, government relations, and other non-research functions. Licensing can overcome some of the managerial diseconomies of scope in such an organization. However, if there were a new system of pharmaceutical innovation that would allow more specialization in R&D versus other functions, that would be an exceedingly beneficial public-policy achievement.

Comments (10)

Trackback URL | Comments RSS Feed

  1. Jimbino says:

    Innovation will be close to worthless once the Chinese start producing the unpatented new drug. The innovator will be left with a prize. That prize will have to be on the order of $1 billion.

    Who will pay the prize? Amerikans.
    Who will pay nothing for huge profits? Chinese

    • Buddy says:

      Innovation is worthless when countries don’t honor patent rights. India, China and other countries that have the incentive to make cheap drugs at the expense of the innovators.

  2. Freedom Lover says:

    I like this idea! Patents do work, but they may lead to some inefficiencies, as well as higher prices for consumers in the short-run. Prize-grants, in the way described here, can reduce some of those while still giving those in R&D plenty of incentives to innovate.

  3. Steve says:

    “Regardless of the outcome of the research undertaken in pursuit of a prize-grant, findings would be immediately placed in the public domain. In contrast, patents set a term of monopoly on the use of information, during which the prices of patented products can be set far above production cost.”

    This is one of the best points made in favor of prize-grants. Monopoly is generally associated with deadweight loss to society, and therefore, even though patents do incentivize innovation, they need to exist on as limited a basis as possible. And prize-grants would be a great alternative for the reasons noted in this post.

    • Matthew says:

      Prices are set at such a high cost for companies to recoup R&D costs. If they can make back the money without monopoly power, then prices can be lower and competition to make that product is encouraged.

  4. SPM says:

    “The FDA itself needs significant reform to stop impeding innovation.”

    Yep, the FDA has contributed to higher drug costs and drugs that could be hugely important becoming available on a less frequent basis than would otherwise be the case.

    • James M. says:

      Perhaps reform of the FDA alone is significant enough to improve pharmaceutical innovation.

  5. Thomas says:

    It would be beneficial to find other avenues to influence innovation, especially in pharmacy, that do not give monopoly power but still give a comparable incentive. Prize grants sound possible, but also flawed.

  6. Devon Herrick says:

    I haven’t thought through all the elements of Arnold Kling’s argument, but this is an interesting idea. That said, I tend to be wary of prizes as a means to foster innovation. Granted, a prize for something like space travel (i.e. X-Prize) has been an effective way to get diverse individuals to compete against each other to advance technology, the benefits of which could not be internalized easily. But as John Graham points out, drug innovation is not the same as space travel.

    It almost sounds like the government saying if you discover a gold mine, we’ll give you a couple nuggets of gold from the mine and then take it from you. The nuggets may, or may not, equal the cost of discovering the mine.

    Of course, the next step would be to decide which discovery is better than another. For example, the 10th (great) drug for hypertension might not be worth as much as the first (bad) drug for hypertension.

  7. Flyover Country American says:

    “That is the great (often unsung) virtue of patents: They do not guarantee one penny of profit. The market determines the value of the product and its ownership can be traded in the capital market during its entire life-cycle, giving continuous signals to other innovators.”

    This is such a good point, and one that is rarely addressed. Researchers who have developed a product will only pay for a patent if they reasonably believe that one will pay off, but they never really know for sure. This risk is another cost they must bear, and any reward, including prize-grants, will have to compensate the business enough to recoup their total costs.